Labor Supply Decisions
and Labor Market Equilibrium
Models of labor supply begin with the assumption
that workers choose combinations of hours-worked and income towards the
goal of maximizing their level of utility given the time constraint of the
number of hours in the day.
In most labor supply models, work is considered to be an undesirable
good. Hours not worked are called leisure hours with leisure time
being the desirable good. The problem of the worker appears as follows:
maximize U = f(Income, Leisure)
s.t.
labor hours + leisure hours < 16 waking hours.
The above expression may be read as "maximize utility (satisfaction) which
is a function of income and leisure hours (both desirable goods) subject to
the number of waking hours available in a day". The above model may be
expressed in terms of labor hours 'L' as follows:
max U = f(w L, 16-L),
where 'w' is the prevailing wage rate. In order to understand the above
model, we will use indifference curve analysis
to examine the effects of a changing wage rate on the number of labor hours
supplied. In figure 1, any point on the curve ICo, which represents
a combination of income and leisure hours, will give the individual the
same level of satisfaction. The individual would be indifferent between point 'R'
and point 'V' on this curve.
figure 1 -- A worker optimum |
|
Points on the curve IC1 represents combinations (or bundles)
of income and leisure that give the individual a higher level of satisfaction.
The line 'XY' represents the budget constraint imposed by the number of
waking hours available in a day (note: the horizontal intercept is equal
to 16) with a slope determined by the real wage rate 'w'1.
In any
indifference curve model, equilibrium for the individual
exists where an indifference curve is just tangent to the budget line.
In the diagram above this occurs at point 'R'. The economic interpretation
of this tangency is that this is the point where the marginal rate ofsubstitution
'MRS'2 between income and leisure time is just equal to the
price of leisure time as measured by the real wage rate. This real wage
represents the opportunity cost of leisure time in terms of foregone
income. An increase in the real wage rate will serve to rotate the budget line upwards
(holding the horizontal intercept constant) and allow for a
tangency with the higher indifference curve as shown in figure 2. As
wages rise, the worker is better off with the ability to earn more with
each hour of work or to maintain current income levels with less work (and
thus the ability to consume more leisure time).
figure 2a -- An increase in
wages (strong substitution effect)
|
figure 2b -- Corresponding Labor Supply Curve
|
|
|
In figure 2a, an increase in the wage rate from $10 per hour
to $12 per hour had the effect of increasing the equilibrium level of
income and decreasing the number of leisure hours (work hours increased)
as indicated by the solid curve IC1. In this case the worker
reduces the amount of leisure time from 8 hours to 6 hours.It could have been the
case that the new equilibrium point was defined by the curve IC1' in figure 3.
In this case the worker reduced the number of work hours upon receiving the wage increase.
Both cases are theoretically possible due to the relative size of the income and
substitution effects. The total change
in leisure hours is called the total effect which is the summation of income and
substitution effects. With a wage increase, leisure time becomes
relatively more expensive (in terms of foregone wages) so the worker will
substitute away from leisure time -- the substitution effect is negative
for a wage increase.
figure 3a -- An increase in
wages (strong income effect)
|
figure 3b -- Corresponding
Labor Supply Curve
|
|
|
Additionally, as income rises with the wage increase individuals will want
to consume more leisure assuming that this good is a normal good --
the income effect for a wage increase is always positive. If the positive income
effect is less than the negative substitution effect, the total effect will be negative
and the worker will consume less leisureand more work. This will lead to a "normal" upward sloping labor
supply curve (the relationship between the real wage and labor hours supplied).
If the income effect is greater than the substitution effect, the worker will consume more
leisure (a positive total effect) and less work. In this case the labor supply curve will be "backward-bending" or represent an inverse relationship between
the wage rate and labor hours supplied (see figure 3).
Empirical studies have concluded that, when we aggregate among all workers,
the labor supply curve is upward sloping and fairly steep (that is, labor supply
decisions are highly wage inelastic or insensitive to changes in the wage rate).
Stronger influences on labor supply come about with changes in population, labor
force participation rates (demographic changes) and immigration flows.
Labor Demand and Market Equilibrium
If we assume that labor supply is positively related to the real wage:
Ls = f[+](w)
then any increase in labor demand 'Ld'
will lead to higher equilibrium
quantities of labor being made available to labor markets at higher real wages.
However, before we discuss equilibrium conditions, we need to take a look at the
determinants of labor demand.
The demand for labor results from producers seeking labor input as one of several
factor inputs into the production process: X = f(L,K,M).
Referring back to a producer optimum,
we find that the profit maximizing firm will hire labor up to the point
where the marginal productivity of the last worker hired 'MPL'
is just equal to the real wage 'w/Px'. This is shown graphically in the diagram
below left by the tangency between the production function (slope = MPL) and
the dotted iso-profit line (slope = w/Px) or in the diagram below right by the
intersection of MPL
and w/P as defined by point 'b':
figure 4 -- The Profit Maximizing Quantity of Labor Input
Changes in labor productivity, either due to technological improvement
or by the addition of more capital per worker will lead to an upward shift
in the production function (more output for each unit of labor input) and an
outward shift in MPL
(each worker is more productive at the margin). Holding
the real wage constant will result in more labor being hired and more output
being produced as shown in the diagrams below:
figure 5 -- An Increase in Labor Productivity
In reality, this type of shock when matched with an upward sloping labor
supply curve should lead to an increase in the real wage. This higher real
wage is necessary to induce more workers into the labor market or to induce
existing workers to work longer hours (in both cases sacrificing leisure time).
This is shown below in figure 6. The increase in productivity shifts the
production function upwards and the marginal product of labor outwards
(b --> d).
However, this excess demand for labor leads to an increase in
nominal and real wages leading to an upward movement along the new labor
demand curve in the right diagram and a counter-clockwise rotation in the
iso-profit line in the left diagram (d -->
f).
Thus a complete model of this type of shock (an increase in productivity)
will lead to a larger equilibrium quantity of labor (L1 --> L2)
and higher real wages.
figure 6 -- An Increase in Labor Productivity
Other types of shocks that may affect labor markets would be in labor supply
either due to changes in labor force participation rates or changes in immigration
patterns. For example, a relaxation of immigration policies (i.e., the H-visa program
of the late 1990's in support of the "tech" boom) would shift labor supply outwards
putting downward pressure on the real wage. This decline in real labor costs might
lead business firms to hire more labor, increasing the level of production and
increasing the output of the economy.
1The real wage rate is just the nominal wage 'W'
divided by the price level 'P' or w = (W/P).
2In this model, the real wage rate 'w' represents this price ratio.
Thus equilibrium is defined as:
MRS = MUleisure/MUincome = w