A Consumer Optimum
A consumer
optimum represents a solution to a
problem facing all individuals -- maximizing the
satisfaction (utility) from consuming different goods and
services subject to the constraint of household income
and product prices. This problem can be described as
follows:
max U = f(X,Y)
s.t. Px(X)
+ Py(Y) < I
In this problem, the objective function is unobservable
leading to the use of assumptions about consumer preferences and diagrammed
through the use of indifference curves.
From our understanding of the utility function and utility
surface we can derive the slope of an indifference curve
as:
the Marginal Rate of Substitution = MRSxy =
MUx/MUy
However, the all variables and parameters in the
budget constraint are observable and thus in defining our
consumer optimum, we assume that this optimum lies on
this constraint. This budget constraint can be written in
several ways. First we can write it as a budget set 'B':
B = {X,Y e R2 | X,Y >
0; Px(X) + Py(Y) < I0}
This budget set represents all combinations of the two
goods that are attainable to the consumer given his level
of income and the the market-determined prices of these
goods. Second, we can write it as a budget constraint
expressed as an exact equality in intercept-slope form:
Y = I0/Py
- (Px/Py)X
The slope of this budget constraint is a relative
price (the price of good-x relative to the price of good-y)
where a change in any price, either in absolute or relative terms, will
lead to a rotation of this constraint. Both this budget constraint and
budget set are shown in figure 1.
figure 1, A
Consumer Optimum |
|
In this diagram, we can note that many
bundles of 'x' and 'y' on IC0 are within this
budget set and thus attainable. However, any point in the
interior of the budget set represents an inefficient use
of income. Point V on this same
indifference curve does represent an efficient use of
income however, the consumer can do better. At this point
the slope of the budget constraint is greater than the
slope of the indifference curve...
Px/Py >
MUx/MUy
or
MUx/Px <
MUy/Py
At this point the marginal utility per dollar spent on
good-x is less that the marginal utility per dollar
spent on good-y. This consumer can increase his level of
satisfaction by reallocating his income to buy more of
good-y (thus MUy will decrease given our assumption of
diminishing marginal utility) and buy less of good-x (MUx
increases). This reallocation of income can be seen as a
movement along the budget constraint from point V
to point R. It is at point R
that the consumer has found an optimum on IC1
where:
MUx/MUy = Px/Py
or MRSxy = Px/Py
This is our condition for a consumer optimum. Note
that any bundle on IC2, although providing a
greater level of satisfaction, lies entirely beyond the
budget set and thus could never include a solution to the
problem facing the consumer.
figure 2,
Exogenous Shocks
In figure 2 we can examine the effect of an increase in consumer income
[click on the "Income (increase)" button. This change leads to a parallel
outward shift in the budget constraint (the slope remains the same since
relative prices have not changed). This increase in income increases
the size of the budget set making a greater number of consumption bundles
attainable to the consumer. This increase in the size of the budget
set implies that the consumer will be better-off as defined with the
new consumer optimum at point T. With this increase
in income, the consumer chooses to consume both more of both goods indicating
that they are both normal goods
to that individual. It is possible that with this type of shock, the
consumer will choose to purchase more of one good and less of the other
(a movement from R to T in the northwest
or southeast direction). In this case one good is normal and the other
an inferior good. It must
be true that at least one good in the consumption bundle is a normal
good. If all goods were inferior, then an increase in income would lead
to a consumer optimum in the interior of the budget set.
Additionally in figure 2, we see the effects of changes in
market price (click any of the appropriate buttons).
In the case of a decrease in the price of good x)the budget
line rotates
outward and the price ratio declines (good-x is less
expensive in absolute and relative terms, good-y is more
expensive in relative terms). This outward rotation also
leads to an increase in the size of the budget set such
that the consumer should be better off. We find that with
this particular price change, the consumer is buying more
of good-x and more of good-y as defined
by a new consumer optimum at point T.
The increase in the amount of good-x
consumed is expected as it is now cheaper to the
consumer. However the increase in consumption of good-y
requires some explanation.
A change in the price of one
particular good has two effects on consumer behavior.
First, is the substitution
effect where the consumer substitutes
towards that good that is relatively cheaper (good-x) and
away from that good that is relatively more expensive
(good-y). Based on the substitution effect alone, we
would expect the consumer to buy more of good-x and less
of good-y. In the case of the latter good, this is not
the case. A decrease in the price of any good in the
consumption bundle also leads to an increase in
purchasing power. The impact of this change is known as
the income effect where,
with this increase in purchasing power, the consumer will
buy more normal goods and fewer inferior goods. In figure
3, we find that the consumer may be substituting away
from good-y but he is also using the increase in
purchasing power to actually buy more of that good.
figure 3,
Price Decomposition
These two effects can be graphically decomposed from
the price reduction. We define the substitution effect as
a comparison of the old price ratio (Px/Py) and the new
(Px*/Py) holding the level of utility constant. We can
see this substitution effect in figure 4, by looking at
the tangency of the original budget constraint (old price
ratio) at point R and a different
tangency on the same indifference curve IC1
defined by the new price ratio at point S.
The income effect is defined as a comparison between the
two levels of satisfaction defined by IC1 and
IC2 holding relative prices constant.
Comparing the two levels of utility acts as a proxy for
changes in purchasing power (similar to a change in the
size of the budget set). This can be seen as the parallel
shift from point S on IC1 to
point T on IC2. We find in
this example that the consumer is substituting towards
good-x and away from good-y and, in addition, he is using
the increase in purchasing power to buy more of both
goods.
This decomposition in price helps in the understanding of the
responsiveness of individual demand to changes in market price. For
a price reduction, the consumer will always demand more of that
good based on the substitution effect. However, the income
effect will either augment demand for this good in the case of
normal goods or offset some of this increase in demand in the case of
inferior goods.
For example, if the good in question is a normal good, then a reduction
in market price will lead to a healthy increase in demanded. The larger the
income effect, the greater the increase in quantity demanded for this good. The individual
demand curve will be relatively flat. If the good in question is an inferior good,
then a reduction in market price will have a smaller impact on demand. With this good being relatively
cheaper the consumer will choose to buy more (the substitution effect). As purchasing power
increases the consumer chooses to buy less (the income effect). These two effects
working on opposite direction will lead to a smaller quantity demanded -- the individual demand
curve will be relatively steep. It could be the case that the income effect exactly offsets the
substitution effect such that the observed change in quantity demanded (the total effect) is unchanged.
Concepts for Review:
- Budget Constraint
- Budget Set
- Consumer Optimum
- Income Effect
- Indifference Curve(s)
- Inferior Good
- Marginal Rate of Substitution
- Marginal Utility
- Normal Good
- Relative Prices
- Substitution Effect
- Total Effect
- Utility (maximization)
- Utility Surface
|